Be Aware Of What Inflation Really Is

inflation courseThe threat of inflation is real

Degussa | In an effort to “fight” the consequences of the politically orchestrated “lockdown”, the Fed pumps vast amounts of money into the economy. It injects base money into the banking system, and it also monetises outstanding debt and finances the US administration’s deficit spending policy by issuing new money. This does not only increase “excess reserves” in the banking system, but it also ramps up the money stock in the hands of firms and consumers.

The goal is to keep people liquid, to make up for lost profits and incomes. The Fed’s money creation policy is already showing the first effects. In late April 2020, the money stock M1 grew 28.5 per cent year-on-year, while the money stock M2 was up 17.8 per cent against last year. The central bank heavily increasing the quantity of money, while economic output contracts – isn’t that inflationary? It sure is, and it would be false to think otherwise.

In this context, it is key to understand what inflation really is. Most people these days think inflation is a rise in consumer goods prices of more than 2 per cent per year – a result of what mainstream economics has been teaching generations of students all around the world. However, equating inflation with changes in consumer goods prices is inadequate and highly deceptive for various reasons. 

Inflation of consumer goods prices ignores the price inflation of many other goods such as – most notably – assets. If and when the prices of, say, stocks, bonds, and real estate go up, and if and when these price increases are not accompanied by the decline of other goods prices, the purchasing power of money falls. This is what happened in the last decades: Consumer goods prices have remained relatively tame, while asset prices inflated.

Those holding assets were on the winning side when the prices rose, while those holding money and fixed claims denominated in money lost out. The former got richer at the expense of the latter. This became possible as central banks, in close cooperation with commercial banks, were allowed a monetary policy of churning out ever-greater amounts of credit and money, provided at ever-lower interest rates. 

The economic truth is that it is the increase in the quantity of money that deserves to be termed inflation, while changes in goods prices are just a possible symptom of an increase in the quantity of money. What an increase in the quantity of money really does is to bring about a redistribution of income and wealth among people. Some will gain at the expense of others. And this does not even have to go hand in hand with goods price increases!

Consider the following case in which the economy contracts heavily. As demand falls, goods prices are under downward pressure. In an effort to prevent prices from falling, the central bank increases the quantity of money in the hands of firms and consumers. Let us assume it succeeds in returning demand towards its original level with goods prices remaining unchanged. At first glance, it appears that there is no inflationary impact – as prices have remained constant.

However, what has happened here is that the increase in the money supply kept the prices of goods from falling. As a result, it benefits the owners of goods who are protected from losses in the form of declining goods prices. This is detrimental for everyone who wishes to buy goods, the holders of money, as they are stripped off the opportunity to purchase goods at a lower price. But that’s not all.

Not all people will, at the same time, obtain an equal share in the increased quantity of money. In fact, some will get more than others. The former are the beneficiaries; the latter miss out. Under the current circumstances, big banks and companies and other financial intermediaries (hedge funds, insurance companies etc.) receive big money, while at the same time, small businesses and employees are fobbed off with a much smaller amount of money. 

What is more, some get the new money earlier than others. The first receivers of the new money are the winners: They can purchase goods at current prices. As the new money moves from hand to hand, thereby increasing goods prices, the late receivers are the losers of the game: They can only purchase goods at higher prices. That said, a policy of expanding the quantity of money undeniably causes income and wealth inequality.

In the current environment, there is mass unemployment in the US, which should put wages under downward pressure. What is more, commodity prices have fallen sharply, in particular oil prices, dampening measures of consumer goods price inflation. However, the quantity of money has increased sharply, largely due to the fact that the Fed is effectively sending newly created money to bank-held deposits.

This development is accompanied by all the effects outlined earlier – no doubt about that. An interesting question is, however, whether or not goods prices will increase. Of course, if we assume that firms and consumers will hold on to their new money balances rather than spending them (meaning a decline in the velocity of money), price inflation may not occur, and even goods price deflation might be the result. 

However, for many people the new money compensates for lost wage income, and so the likelihood that the new money will be spent on food, clothes, etc. is relatively high. In other words, the new money is likely to find its way into the demand for goods and services. In view of a reduced goods supply, there is good reason to fear that consumer goods price inflation is about to accelerate – despite the latest oil price crash.

All the more so if and when the lockdown comes to an end sooner rather than later, letting the economy to return to “normal”. In such an environment the “monetary overhang” created by the increase in the quantity of money can almost definitely be expected to drive up consumer and producer goods prices – if and when firms and consumers return towards their original spending behaviour.

One thing, however, appears to the very likely: That the Fed’s monetary expansion will drive up asset prices: the prices for stocks, real estate, etc. The latest co-movement of the Fed’s balance sheet expansion and the S&P 500 stock market index suggests exactly that: The inflation policy is alive and kicking, as created by the Fed in the past. This time, however, to an unprecedented extent.

The lesson to learn for any investor is this: It is very likely that the US-dollar as well as all other unbacked paper currencies around the world will continue to suffer: The currencies’ purchasing power is the first victim of central banks’ “rescue policies”. The debasement will come either through asset price inflation and/or consumer price inflation or a combination of both. As things stand, it is difficult to imagine that this scenario will not occur.

About the Author

The Corner
The Corner has a team of on-the-ground reporters in capital cities ranging from New York to Beijing. Their stories are edited by the teams at the Spanish magazine Consejeros (for members of companies’ boards of directors) and at the stock market news site Consenso Del Mercado (market consensus). They have worked in economics and communication for over 25 years.